Pages

Monday, May 27, 2013

Mongolia’s sovereign bond has teething problems




Mongolia’s sovereign bond has teething problems


Debut bond rebounded after political scuffle; Investment opportunities limited elsewhere


When Mongolia issued its debut sovereign bond in late November, international investors showed immediate and keen interest. But a spat within the coalition government resulted in the bond’s price plummeting dramatically, threatening to completely undermine the initial positive reaction. In the face of this setback, Mongolia has gone into overdrive in its efforts to paint the bond issue in a positive light. Alisher Ali, chairman of Silk Road Finance, a frontier markets investment group Alisher Ali, chairman of Silk Road Finance, a frontier markets investment group "The first sovereign issue by the Mongolian government was clearly a major success," says Alisher Ali, chairman of Silk Road Finance, a frontier markets investment group. "The sovereign bond was the largest-ever issue among all frontier markets for a debut – the issue broke a number of records." Mongolia issued $1.5 billion in debt in five-year and 10-year tranches. The landmark transaction attracted an order book in excess of $15 billion. Both tranches priced at the tight end of final price guidance, at 4.125% to 4.25% for the five-year tranche and 5.125% to 5.25% for the 10-year tranche. Bank of America Merrill Lynch, Deutsche Bank, HSBC and JPMorgan were the joint bookrunners for the sale. The bond’s sudden slump in value by $7 to $8 came after members of Mongolia’s fragile government, the Mongolian People’s Revolutionary Party, announced that the party would quit the ruling coalition, led by the Democratic Party, in protest at MPRP leader Nambar Enkhbayar’s arrest following corruption charges. "Here in Mongolia, people were actually quite surprised that the international community paid so much attention to what was going on in local politics," says Randolph Koppa, president of the Trade and Development Bank of Mongolia. "[They have] never really cared before, but since the bond, all eyes are on Mongolia. Political activities and the related rhetoric meant mainly for local consumption are being misjudged. Most people in the west do not have any idea how Mongolian politics work as yet." According to Ali, investors panicked as a result of greater political tension. "The bond issue was so widely distributed and inevitably, some investors – those not fully aware of the political fundamentals in Mongolia – panicked and wanted out," he says. "The fact is that there has been political volatility in Mongolia since April, and this was priced in." Indeed, the likelihood that the coalition government in Mongolia would fall apart even if the MPRP decided to withdraw was minimal. A report by Origo Partners, a private equity investment company based in China, highlights that the threat was only meant as a high-profile warning to the authorities by the MPRP. "The fact that MPRP ministers have not actually submitted their resignations indicates to us that this political action was aimed primarily at influencing the outcome of the court ruling," says the report. "Following the finalization of Enkhbayar’s case we expect the usual condemnation and possibly other political actions of protest from the MPRP, but not the actual exit from... the coalition government." Moreover, according to the report, the fact that the bonds soon rebounded shows that the market has largely ignored the potential for further political controversy from the MPRP leading to government collapse. The latest tussle could even be beneficial for Mongolia and bring the frontier market to the fore. "The political [tensions]... brought attention to Mongolia. People are new to the Mongolian story, but the bond issue and the momentary [political] hiccup that followed will demand investor interest," says Ali. Koppa says: "The week that Mongolia went on the road to drum up interest for their bond, there was no bad news. Talks surrounding the fiscal cliff were just about to start and the Greek crisis looked as if it was cooling down. Investors saw this as a good opportunity, especially for diversification of their portfolios by including a new country from a more dynamic region of the world." Indeed, the Mongolian bond was popular because investor opportunities elsewhere are limited. Low interest rates in developed economies amid the eurozone crisis and the fiscal cliff have also spurred investors to seek more exotic, high-yielding bonds, while at the same time mainstream emerging market names including Mexico, South Africa and Indonesia have yields at record lows. "Frontier markets like Mongolia offer yield and diversification and so are a good buy," says Ali. The size of Mongolia’s debut bond is approximately equal to 43% of the country’s debt to GDP ratio, and is about 15% of GDP in absolute terms. Moreover, the deal, the biggest in Asia for more than a decade, is so large that the country does not have the net international foreign exchange reserves to cover it.


Mongolia might face 'major macroeconomic instability'


Mongolia might face 'major macroeconomic instability'


Mongolia might face 'major macroeconomic instability', says top analyst


While we want you to share, we ask you use the functions on-site rather than copy/paste. See T's & C's for details. http://www.euromoney.com/Article/3208760/ChannelPage/0/AssetCategory/766/Mongolia-might-face-major-macroeconomic-instability-says-top-analyst.html?copyrightInfo=true



Mongolia might face 'major macroeconomic instability', says top analyst by Kanika Saigal Against the backdrop of a more friendly posture towards international investors, Mongolia’s commodity-reliant economy is poised for more cyclical volatility, warns a top central Asian investor. 




Further reading Mongolia’s sovereign bond has teething problems Mongolia bond sets off EM bond bubble concerns Markets lag Mongolia’s mining rise Mongolia’s economy faces macroeconomic headwinds this year as drivers for expansion – credit growth and commodities – soften against the backdrop of an imbalanced economy, warns a top Mongolian investor. The comments come despite a relaxation in Mongolia’s investment law established last May – aimed at encouraging a resurgence in foreign direct investment – which has restored confidence in the country's medium- and long-term growth prospects. Alisher Ali, founder and chairman of Silk Road Finance Alisher Ali, founder and chairman of Silk Road Finance, a frontier markets investment group, warns that the country – rich in natural resources, including gold, copper and coking coal – faces weak growth this year amid a slowdown in commodity demand. “The growth slowdown in China and the decline in commodity prices globally could have a negative effect on the economy in Mongolia,” says Ali. Mongolian export revenues have already been hit. In 2012, China accounted for 92.6% of Mongolian exports, totalling $4.38 billion. In Mongolia, exports declined nearly 8% year-to-date in the first quarter this year. “A recovery in export prices will depend on demand for commodities from China,” says Ali. Indeed, the decline in commodity prices and exports hit government revenues at a time of substantial infrastructure and development projects. “Between 2010 and 2012, government expenditure nearly doubled," says Ali. "At the same time, government revenue increased by only 60%." In 2012, the budget deficit reached a decade high of 8.4% of GDP. Although Mongolia is expected to maintain one of the highest economic growth rates in the world, uncertainty surrounding economic prospects encouraged the World Bank to lower its estimate for Mongolia’s economic expansion in 2013 to 13% compared with an earlier forecast of 16.2%. In the first quarter of the year, the economy expanded at a slower-than-expected pace at 7.7% year-on-year compared with 17% over the corresponding period in 2012. Banking is also under pressure. The sector, which accounts for more than 95% of the financial system in terms of assets, grew by 28% in 2012, reaching MNT11,992 billion ($8.6 billion), down from a record 50% increase in 2011. “While expansionary fiscal policy and increasing funding demand from household sectors supported growth [in the banking sector], the drop in growth was largely due to the slowdown in economic growth because of lower coal prices and volumes in exports,” says Ali. Mongolia has also borrowed more than $2 billion in international debt markets to finance infrastructure projects, close to 20% of GDP. “With current spending trend continuing, the government is likely to face the need to balance its budget, whilst paying back foreign debt,” says Ali. “Mongolia needs a wide political consensus and action on fiscal discipline or face major macroeconomic instability in coming years.” Reversing the trend Mongolia made progress when it relaxed a foreign investment law established last May. The Strategic Entities Foreign Investment Law limited international investors to 49% stakes in sectors, including the mining industry, after approval from the government. Restrictions on investment in Mongolia saw FDI into the country drop dramatically, and local investors lacked the ability to support the mining sector and subsequent economic growth. In 2012, investment into the country fell by 17% to $3.9 billion. An amendment passed on April 19 will make privately owned companies exempt from the law and aims to kick-start investment into the country again. The revision of the investment law sends a good signal to international investors and an important about-face on policies regarding resource nationalism, says Ali, adding: “But although the law has been partially reversed, one of the major challenges faced by Mongolia is to rebuild investor confidence.” Production from the Oyu Tolgoi mine, one of the world’s largest copper mines and Mongolia’s single largest investment project, is aimed at supporting the economy. The government expects export volumes of copper to nearly double and gold more than double, primarily due to the start of production at Oyu Tolgoi in 2013. Although Silk Road Finance is bullish on the country's medium- and long-term growth prospects, Ali warned that fiscal indiscipline, growing budgetary pressures, structural inflation and a cooling banking sector pose headwinds for the economy after recent years of breakneck expansion.



Against the backdrop of a more friendly posture towards international investors, Mongolia’s commodity-reliant economy is poised for more cyclical volatility, warns a top central Asian


While we want you to share, we ask you use the functions on-site rather than copy/paste. See T's & C's for details. http://www.euromoney.com/Article/3208760/ChannelPage/0/AssetCategory/766/Mongolia-might-face-major-macroeconomic-instability-says-top-analyst.html?copyrightInfo=true

Mongolia might face 'major macroeconomic instability', says top analyst

Mongolia’s sovereign bond has teething problems by Kanika Saigal Debut bond rebounded after political scuffle; Investment opportunities limited elsewhere Further reading Debt capital markets poised to disintermediate bank lending in Asia Mongolia bond sets off EM bond bubble concerns When Mongolia issued its debut sovereign bond in late November, international investors showed immediate and keen interest. But a spat within the coalition government resulted in the bond’s price plummeting dramatically, threatening to completely undermine the initial positive reaction. In the face of this setback, Mongolia has gone into overdrive in its efforts to paint the bond issue in a positive light. Alisher Ali, chairman of Silk Road Finance, a frontier markets investment group Alisher Ali, chairman of Silk Road Finance, a frontier markets investment group "The first sovereign issue by the Mongolian government was clearly a major success," says Alisher Ali, chairman of Silk Road Finance, a frontier markets investment group. "The sovereign bond was the largest-ever issue among all frontier markets for a debut – the issue broke a number of records." Mongolia issued $1.5 billion in debt in five-year and 10-year tranches. The landmark transaction attracted an order book in excess of $15 billion. Both tranches priced at the tight end of final price guidance, at 4.125% to 4.25% for the five-year tranche and 5.125% to 5.25% for the 10-year tranche. Bank of America Merrill Lynch, Deutsche Bank, HSBC and JPMorgan were the joint bookrunners for the sale. The bond’s sudden slump in value by $7 to $8 came after members of Mongolia’s fragile government, the Mongolian People’s Revolutionary Party, announced that the party would quit the ruling coalition, led by the Democratic Party, in protest at MPRP leader Nambar Enkhbayar’s arrest following corruption charges. "Here in Mongolia, people were actually quite surprised that the international community paid so much attention to what was going on in local politics," says Randolph Koppa, president of the Trade and Development Bank of Mongolia. "[They have] never really cared before, but since the bond, all eyes are on Mongolia. Political activities and the related rhetoric meant mainly for local consumption are being misjudged. Most people in the west do not have any idea how Mongolian politics work as yet." According to Ali, investors panicked as a result of greater political tension. "The bond issue was so widely distributed and inevitably, some investors – those not fully aware of the political fundamentals in Mongolia – panicked and wanted out," he says. "The fact is that there has been political volatility in Mongolia since April, and this was priced in." Indeed, the likelihood that the coalition government in Mongolia would fall apart even if the MPRP decided to withdraw was minimal. A report by Origo Partners, a private equity investment company based in China, highlights that the threat was only meant as a high-profile warning to the authorities by the MPRP. "The fact that MPRP ministers have not actually submitted their resignations indicates to us that this political action was aimed primarily at influencing the outcome of the court ruling," says the report. "Following the finalization of Enkhbayar’s case we expect the usual condemnation and possibly other political actions of protest from the MPRP, but not the actual exit from... the coalition government." Moreover, according to the report, the fact that the bonds soon rebounded shows that the market has largely ignored the potential for further political controversy from the MPRP leading to government collapse. The latest tussle could even be beneficial for Mongolia and bring the frontier market to the fore. "The political [tensions]... brought attention to Mongolia. People are new to the Mongolian story, but the bond issue and the momentary [political] hiccup that followed will demand investor interest," says Ali. Koppa says: "The week that Mongolia went on the road to drum up interest for their bond, there was no bad news. Talks surrounding the fiscal cliff were just about to start and the Greek crisis looked as if it was cooling down. Investors saw this as a good opportunity, especially for diversification of their portfolios by including a new country from a more dynamic region of the world." Indeed, the Mongolian bond was popular because investor opportunities elsewhere are limited. Low interest rates in developed economies amid the eurozone crisis and the fiscal cliff have also spurred investors to seek more exotic, high-yielding bonds, while at the same time mainstream emerging market names including Mexico, South Africa and Indonesia have yields at record lows. "Frontier markets like Mongolia offer yield and diversification and so are a good buy," says Ali. The size of Mongolia’s debut bond is approximately equal to 43% of the country’s debt to GDP ratio, and is about 15% of GDP in absolute terms. Moreover, the deal, the biggest in Asia for more than a decade, is so large that the country does not have the net international foreign exchange reserves to cover it.


While we want you to share, we ask you use the functions on-site rather than copy/paste. See T's & C's for details. http://www.euromoney.com/Article/3135680/Category/14/ChannelPage/0/Mongolias-sovereign-bond-has-teething-problems.html?copyrightInfo=true
Mongolia’s sovereign bond has teething problems by Kanika Saigal Debut bond rebounded after political scuffle; Investment opportunities limited elsewhere Further reading Debt capital markets poised to disintermediate bank lending in Asia Mongolia bond sets off EM bond bubble concerns When Mongolia issued its debut sovereign bond in late November, international investors showed immediate and keen interest. But a spat within the coalition government resulted in the bond’s price plummeting dramatically, threatening to completely undermine the initial positive reaction. In the face of this setback, Mongolia has gone into overdrive in its efforts to paint the bond issue in a positive light. Alisher Ali, chairman of Silk Road Finance, a frontier markets investment group Alisher Ali, chairman of Silk Road Finance, a frontier markets investment group "The first sovereign issue by the Mongolian government was clearly a major success," says Alisher Ali, chairman of Silk Road Finance, a frontier markets investment group. "The sovereign bond was the largest-ever issue among all frontier markets for a debut – the issue broke a number of records." Mongolia issued $1.5 billion in debt in five-year and 10-year tranches. The landmark transaction attracted an order book in excess of $15 billion. Both tranches priced at the tight end of final price guidance, at 4.125% to 4.25% for the five-year tranche and 5.125% to 5.25% for the 10-year tranche. Bank of America Merrill Lynch, Deutsche Bank, HSBC and JPMorgan were the joint bookrunners for the sale. The bond’s sudden slump in value by $7 to $8 came after members of Mongolia’s fragile government, the Mongolian People’s Revolutionary Party, announced that the party would quit the ruling coalition, led by the Democratic Party, in protest at MPRP leader Nambar Enkhbayar’s arrest following corruption charges. "Here in Mongolia, people were actually quite surprised that the international community paid so much attention to what was going on in local politics," says Randolph Koppa, president of the Trade and Development Bank of Mongolia. "[They have] never really cared before, but since the bond, all eyes are on Mongolia. Political activities and the related rhetoric meant mainly for local consumption are being misjudged. Most people in the west do not have any idea how Mongolian politics work as yet." According to Ali, investors panicked as a result of greater political tension. "The bond issue was so widely distributed and inevitably, some investors – those not fully aware of the political fundamentals in Mongolia – panicked and wanted out," he says. "The fact is that there has been political volatility in Mongolia since April, and this was priced in." Indeed, the likelihood that the coalition government in Mongolia would fall apart even if the MPRP decided to withdraw was minimal. A report by Origo Partners, a private equity investment company based in China, highlights that the threat was only meant as a high-profile warning to the authorities by the MPRP. "The fact that MPRP ministers have not actually submitted their resignations indicates to us that this political action was aimed primarily at influencing the outcome of the court ruling," says the report. "Following the finalization of Enkhbayar’s case we expect the usual condemnation and possibly other political actions of protest from the MPRP, but not the actual exit from... the coalition government." Moreover, according to the report, the fact that the bonds soon rebounded shows that the market has largely ignored the potential for further political controversy from the MPRP leading to government collapse. The latest tussle could even be beneficial for Mongolia and bring the frontier market to the fore. "The political [tensions]... brought attention to Mongolia. People are new to the Mongolian story, but the bond issue and the momentary [political] hiccup that followed will demand investor interest," says Ali. Koppa says: "The week that Mongolia went on the road to drum up interest for their bond, there was no bad news. Talks surrounding the fiscal cliff were just about to start and the Greek crisis looked as if it was cooling down. Investors saw this as a good opportunity, especially for diversification of their portfolios by including a new country from a more dynamic region of the world." Indeed, the Mongolian bond was popular because investor opportunities elsewhere are limited. Low interest rates in developed economies amid the eurozone crisis and the fiscal cliff have also spurred investors to seek more exotic, high-yielding bonds, while at the same time mainstream emerging market names including Mexico, South Africa and Indonesia have yields at record lows. "Frontier markets like Mongolia offer yield and diversification and so are a good buy," says Ali. The size of Mongolia’s debut bond is approximately equal to 43% of the country’s debt to GDP ratio, and is about 15% of GDP in absolute terms. Moreover, the deal, the biggest in Asia for more than a decade, is so large that the country does not have the net international foreign exchange reserves to cover it.


While we want you to share, we ask you use the functions on-site rather than copy/paste. See T's & C's for details. http://www.euromoney.com/Article/3135680/Category/14/ChannelPage/0/Mongolias-sovereign-bond-has-teething-problems.html?copyrightInfo=true

Korea’s Capitalistic Planning Model: Policy Lessons for Mongolia*


Korea’s Capitalistic Planning Model:
Policy Lessons for Mongolia


THE JOURNAL OF THE KOREAN ECONOMY, Vol. 11, No. 1 (April 2010) 177-194



Korea’s Capitalistic Planning Model:

Policy Lessons for Mongolia*


Inchul Kim**
Mongolia transitioned from a socialist economy to a free market system in the early 1990s. Its status as a land-locked country with abundant natural resources and but a small population of only 3 million has prompted the growth of livestock herding and mining as the two major industries. This dependence has rendered Mongolia‘s economy susceptible to fluctuations in the world market.
This paper analyzes Korea‘s model of long-term planning to highlight the essential conditions for economics success, inclusive of strong political leadership and labor migration from the rural sector to urban sectors. Mongolia is urged to adopt a capitalistic planning model to secure long term development, placing particular emphasis on the development of a proper macroeconomic management strategy to lessen the impact of the 2008 global financial crisis.
JEL Classification: O21, F41, F43
Keywords: economic planning, state leadership, economic think tanks,
policy mix
* Received January 3, 2010. Accepted April 5, 2010. The author is indebted to anonymous referees for critical and helpful comments. However, the author is entirely responsible for any remaining errors. This is a revised version of the paper that was presented at the 2009 Korea-Mongolia Seminar held in Ulaan Baatar, Mongolia over 5-6 June 2009.
** Professor of economics, Sungkyunkwan University, Seoul, Korea, Tel: 82-2-760-0428, Fax: 82-2-745-4367, E-mail: ickim@skku.ac.kr
178 Inchul Kim

1. THE CAPITALISTIC PLANNING MODEL
1.1. Economic Planning in a Capitalist Country
Korea went through seven rounds of the Five Year Economic Plan (FEP) from 1962-1996. The first FEP was a great success. Its formulation was reliant nation had to rely on foreign expertise. The featured planning techniques lacked sophistication, partly owing to the paucity of statistical data. Notwithstanding these deficiencies, the Korean economy performed well with growth rates for each of the five year periods exceeding their targets.
Economic planning had long been exclusively associated with socialist countries. After World War II, however, many African and Asian countries sought to implement planning measures in their respective economies. As the recipients of economic aid from Western donor countries, they were entitled to concessionary loans from international financial organizations.
There are far more differences than similarities between socialist and capitalist planning. First of all, economic goals in democratic countries represent the aims of the majority of people, policy makers are themselves democratically elected by the people. Therefore, national goals and intermediate targets in long-term plans reflect the overall preferences of the majority of the people.
Secondly, the planning utilized by the capitalist countries is a lot more flexible than communism. Along with trade and financial liberalization, national economies are heavily dependent upon one another, and they are exposed to internal and external shocks. For example, planning authorities can change policy instruments, and revise forecasts of their target variables if their initial projection of the future state variables proves inaccurate.
1.2. The Conditions for Successful Development Planning
Development planning provides economic agents with basic policy
Korea’s Capitalistic Planning Model: Policy Lessons for Mongolia 179
objectives germane to the domestic and external economy. It sets national economic priorities and identifies problem areas, by passing through the consensus-building process and seeking appropriate policy instruments. Through their involvement, bureaucrats receive training on how to expedite the flow of information.
The success of development planning is critically dependent upon efficient and effective implementation. Its prerequisites are political stability and political leadership. In the early stage of development, human resources are poor. The state leader therefore needs to demonstrate the necessity of development planning to attain national consensus for massive investments and borrowing from abroad.
The Korean people greeted President Park as a hero, at least in the beginning of his first term when a military coup brought him to power in 1961. The public generally characterized Park a benevolent dictator in recognition of how his authoritarian regime initiated a series of successful economic reforms. However, a declared intent to ensconce himself in the Presidency on a permanent basis eventually undermined his popularity.

1.3. Korea’s Economic Planning System
Six agents are integral to the functioning of Korea‘s system of economic planning: the state leader, the planning office, the budget office, the statistical office, the media, and the nation‘s think tanks. Figure 1 illustrates how each plays a very distinctive and important role.
The diagram in figure 1 resembles a walking robot. The activation of the six organs implements the internally consistent economic plans. The process can be described as the preparation of Korea‘s long-term development plans through active interactions among the various planning organizations. Top political leaders assume full responsibility for the planning process. National goals reflect the public‘s general preferences. Specialists assist planners to design long-term plans by providing special knowledge and planning techniques. In addition, the three government
180 Inchul Kim
Figure 1 Korea’s Economic Planning System
 


agencies cooperate together to achieve a mutual objective. The planning office plays the central role when interacting with the budget and statistical offices. The mass media also plays a critical role in checking for the potential adverse effects of the plans, thereby influencing the prioritization of national goals.
2. KOREA’S DEVELOPMENT STRATEGY
DURING 1962-1997
2.1. State leadership and Economic Performance
Korea went through seven rounds of Five-year Economic Plans from 1962-1997. During this period Korea achieved high growth, and much credit should be given to the government for its planning strategy. Korea
Korea’s Capitalistic Planning Model: Policy Lessons for Mongolia 181
had to prepare long-term development plans in order to receive aid from the US and to receive concessionary loans from other international organizations such as the Asia Development Bank, the World Bank and the IMF (International Monetary Fund).
During the seven plan periods, five state leaders held the presidential office in Korea. President Park, Chung Hee controlled the country from 1961 until his assassination in October 1979. The Korean constitution authorized Prime Minister Choi, Kyu Ha to automatically assume the presidency. President Choi kept his presidential position until May 1981. During his short presidency, President Choi did not provide much influence on the economy, acting merely as a care-taker during a transitional period. General Chun held the reins of power during President Choi‘s presidency.
After President Chun had ruled for seven years, he peacefully abdicated to his military friend, General Roh, Tae Woo in 1988. General Roh took power on account of a presidential election largely influenced by the incumbent President Chun. Having been complacent with the legitimacy of his power, President Roh did not emphasize the nation‘s economic growth to the same extent as his predecessors. He sought to accommodate workers‘ demands. Consequently, national competitiveness began to rapidly weaken. After President Roh, a civilian President, Kim, Young Sam governed Korea from 1992-1997.
A brief view of Korea‘s economic conditions under the different regimes is provided in table 1. In the early 1960s, President Park laid the foundation for high-speed economic growth, and successfully initiated long-term planning for the first time. His planning strategy worked quite well, and the economy grew rapidly. He initiated a national campaign, the ―New Village Movement‖ which emphasized the spirit of self-help and self-support, and provided rewards to competent and honest bureaucrats.
President Chun exercised strong leverage over the National Assembly and the government, and was able to get his agenda easily passed in the legislature. Luckily, the international environment was very favorable for
182 Inchul Kim
Table 1 Korea’s Economic Performance by Regime
President
Date
5-Year Plans
Target
Growth Rate*
(%)
Actual
Growth Rate*
(%)
Park, Chung Hee
(Military)
1961. 5-1979. 10
1) 1962-1966
2) 1967-1971
3) 1972-1976
4) 1977-1981
7.1
7.0
8.6
9.2
7.8
9.6
9.7
5.8
Chun, Doo Hwan
(Military)
1981. 5-1988. 2
5) 1982-1986
6) 1987-1991
7.5
7.3
8.6
10
Roh, Tae Woo
(Military)
1988. 5-1993. 2
6) 1987-1991
7) 1993-1997
7.3
7.5
10
7
Kim, Young Sam
(Civilian)
1993. 2-1998. 2
7) 1993-1997
7.5
7
Sources: National Statistical Office, Various Issues of Annual Statistical Reports. * refers to the average economic growth rate over a 5 year period.
Korea. World energy prices and international interest rates were substantially low, and the value of the Japanese yen stayed at a relatively high level as compared to the U.S. dollar. This allowed Korea to compete with Japan in exporting goods to the U.S. and other countries. Because of these favorable factors, Korea enjoyed high growth, stable prices, and large trade surpluses during 1986-1989. It was about this time that the Korean firms began to substantially expand and become internationally competitive.
When President Roh took over in 1988, the Korean economy had already begun to lose its dynamism. President Roh‘s conciliatory approach afforded labor activists greater latitude to strike. Labor‘s relationship with management consequently deteriorated rapidly. The macroeconomic indicators appeared reasonable, but cracks began to appear in the backbone of the economy.
Korea’s Capitalistic Planning Model: Policy Lessons for Mongolia 183
The seventh 5 year economic plan over the period of 1992-1996 warrants a special mention. In March 1992, the seventh 5 year plan was announced by President Roh. However, when President Kim, Young Sam took over the government in March 1992, he discarded the announced seventh 5 year plan and implemented the New Economy Five Year Plan (1993-1997). Upon his presidential inauguration, President Kim announced the ―New Economy 100 Day Plan‖ to quickly boost the Korean economy. The Plan emphasized globalization, industrialization, technological advancement, and social overhead capital
During the seven rounds of the 5 year economic planning periods (1962-1997), four presidents ruled Korea. With the exception of Kim, Young Sam, all came from military backgrounds. Their politics were typically viewed as dictatorial, whereas in economic terms they were feted as heroes. Their respective military regime outperformed all previous efforts at economic management. The actual growth rates mostly exceeded their target growth rates. Among the military dictators, President Park ruled Korea for the longest time, being 18 years, and his economic performance was more outstanding than any other period of Korea‘s history.
2.2. Korea’s Industrialization
Korea‘s industrialization commenced in 1962, and has reached its apogee during the fifth economic planning period (1982-1986). As reported in table 2, the GDP share of mining and manufacture was 20.5% during the period of the first plan. It attained its highest level, 32.6% during the fifth period, before declining to a level of 25.9% during 1993-1997. In contrast, Korea‘s agricultural sector declined over the entire period. The GDP share of agriculture, forestry, and fishery was 34.9% for the first period, falling to only 5.7% for the last period (1993-1997). Strikingly, the GDP share of social- overhead capital and other services continuously increased from 44.6% in the first period to 68.4% in the last period. Evidently, the services sector plays a dominant role in Korea. The structural change in both the light
184 Inchul Kim
Table 2 Changes in Industrial Structure
Planning Period
Industrial Structure
Manufacturing
Structure
Agriculture,
Forestry, and
Fishery
Mining and
Manufacture
SOC and
Others
Light
Industry
HCI
1st EDP Period
(1962-1966)
34.9
(34.0)
20.5
(27.2)
44.6
(38.8)
65.9
34.1
2nd EDP Period
(1967-1971)
27
(34.0)
22.3
(26.8)
50.7
(39.2)
60.7
39.3
3rd EDP Period
(1972-1976)
23.7
(22.4)
28.6
(27.9)
47.7
(49.7)
53.2
46.8
4th EDP Period
(1977-1981)
17.2
(18.5)
30
(40.9)
52.8
(40.6)
47.1
52.9
5th EDP Period
(1982-1986)
11.5
(12.2)
32.6
(31.0)
55.9
(56.9)
40.4
59.6
6th EDP Period
(1987-1991)
8
(10.1)
28.6
(32.9)
63.4
(59.0)
31.7
68.3
New Economic
Plan Period
(1993-1997)
5.7
25.9
68.4
22.8
77.2
Note: Figures in parentheses represent the target rates.
Source: Dal Hyun Kim (2009).
industry and heavy/chemical industry (HCI), is striking. Korea‘s light industry has steadily shrunk whereas its HCI has been expanding.
Korea‘s population is almost 50 million. During the period 1960s-1970s, Korea had an advantage in terms of surplus labor. Korean leaders have tried to redirect the surplus labor from agriculture to the manufacturing sector. The influence of Nobel Prize winning economist Professor Arthur Lewis‘ seminal work (1955) is apparent in this approach. Korea‘s labor migration strategy proved successful. However, this strategy is not practical for a small but resources-rich country such as Mongolia.
Korea’s Capitalistic Planning Model: Policy Lessons for Mongolia 185
3. MONGOLIA’S ECONOMIC SITUATION
3.1. The Real-Side Economy
Mongolia was a communist country until the collapse of the Soviet Union in 1989. In 1990 Mongolia began its transition to a democratic market economy. The New Constitution of 1992 formalized democratic reforms. This has extended to economic management and development of its market infrastructure.
Mongolia is a land-locked country with abundant natural resources, neighbored by China and Russia. See figure 2. While its territory is as huge as 156,000km2, its population is a mere 3 million. In contrast, South Korea‘s territory is only 80,000km2 with its population being 50 million. The major urban centers include: Ulaanbaatar (800,000), Darkhan (72,000), Erdenet (63,000), Tchoibalsan (40,000), and Soukhe Baatar (23,000). The numbers in parentheses indicate the size of population as of 2005. In 2008 approximately 60% of its population could be classified as urban dwellers.
Mongolia is solely dependent on nomadic livestock husbandry. Agriculture accounts for 36% of employment and 19% of GDP. About 80% of agricultural production is animal-based, with the remaining 20% comprised of wheat. Only 1% (1.35 million hectares) of land is arable, and more than 80% of its area supports livestock herding. Livestock herding and mining are the two major industries. Mongolian herds predominantly consist of goats and sheep. Agricultural production is subject to climactic fluctuations, most notably the so-called ―dzud‖ — a winter disaster that covers pastures with ice and causes mass starvation of livestock. Recent occurrences between 1996-1997, 1999-2000 and 2000-2001 were notable for their severity, particularly the last dzud, which killed 13% of the total livestock.
Banking and tourism in the urban areas are becoming important industries in Mongolia. According to the 2007/8 Household Socio-Economic Survey, rural poverty combined with unemployment and inflation fueled migration
186 Inchul Kim
Figure 2 Major Cities in Mongolia
from the countryside to Ulaanbaatar. Nevertheless, pastoral livestock herding and mining in the rural areas are still important industries. Owing to the small population and the abundant natural resources in the rural areas, Mongolia will have to simultaneously develop both the rural and urban sectors. As of the end of 2000, the sector allocation of Mongolia‘s GDP is as follows: agriculture (33%), industry (19%), and services (48%). In contrast, in Korea, the GDP is comprised of agriculture (5.7%), industry (25.9%), and services (68.4 %).
To achieve a long term sustainable growth, Mongolians will need to place high value on its economic objectives such as human development and quality of living, harmony between growth and environment, and the advancement of science and technology.
Korea’s Capitalistic Planning Model: Policy Lessons for Mongolia 187
3.2. Macroeconomic Management
Mongolia has enjoyed robust economic growth, averaging 9% per year over 2007-2009. Stronger economic growth is expected over the medium term mainly due to the mining sector. However, the 2008 global financial crisis devastated the economy. Falling mineral prices and a steep drop in external demand slowed its economy. Inflation has eased significantly from 33.7% in August 2008 to 4.9% in July 2009. Mongolia‘s long-term sustainable growth is dependent on structural reforms, including increased competition in the non-mining sector and deeper integration into the global economy.
Table 3 shows Mongolia‘s key indicators from 2003-2009. The rate of unemployment has been steadily decreasing since 2004. This is consistent with its high growth trend. The average annual growth rate for the period 2003-2008 was 8.8%. However, inflation has fluctuated wildly, obliging the government to stabilize the economy. Government spending on public sector wages, along with social overhead capital, increased in 2008. The government balance ratio was around 3% from 2005-2007 but dropped to a negative 5% in 2008.
The country‘s trade account and current account balances recorded deficits in 2008, which appears set to continue owing to reductions in export revenue. However, foreign exchange reserves were increasing, while the value of ‗Togrok‘, the Mongolian currency has been decreasing. In view of the real effective exchange rates, the competitiveness of the Mongolian export products is overall being maintained in the world market.
Considering the goal variables of inflation and the current account balances as well as the policy variables of fiscal spending and the exchange rate, we can find a desirable policy direction for Mongolia by adopting the policy-mix model developed by Robert Mundell (1962).
188 Inchul Kim
Table 3 Mongolia’s Key Economic Indicators
2005
2006
2007
2008
Real GDP Growth (%)
7.3
8.6
10.2
8.9
Nominal GDP ($ million)
2,307
3,156
3,930
5,258
GDP per Capita (USD)
900
1,214
1,491
1,960
Unemployment (%)
3.3
3.2
2.8
2.8
Consumer Price Index (%)
9.6
5.9
14.1
23.2
Government Balance (% of GDP)
2.6
3.3
2.8
–5.0
Trade Balance ($ million)
–99.5
136.2
–52.4
–612.6
Exports of Goods ($ million)
1,066.1
1,543.9
1,950.7
2,539.3
Copper Export (%)
14.7
94.8
27.7
3.0
Imports of Goods ($ million)
1,165.6
1,407.7
211.7
3,615.8
Current Account Balance ($ million)
29.7
221.6
264.8
–729.9
Foreign Direct Investment ($ million)
257.6
289.6
360.0
585.5
External Debt ($ million)
1,360.0
1,413.9
1,528.7
1,600.5
Foreign Reserves Gross ($ million)
333.1
718.0
1,000.6
656.7
Domestic Credit (%)
18.8
–3.1
78.4
60.6
Short-term Interest Rate (% per annum)
3.7
5.1
8.4
9.8
Exchange Rate (Togrok/USD)
1,221.0
1,165.0
1,170.0
1,267.5
Real Effective Exchange Rate (2006=100)
99.6
102.8
104.8
127.4
Source: The World Bank‘s Monthly Economic Update, December 2009.
4. APPROPRIATE USE OF POLICY INSTRUMENTS
To illustrate how the central bank can implement macroeconomic policies, we adopt the Mundell model (1962) to the internal and external balance of
Korea’s Capitalistic Planning Model: Policy Lessons for Mongolia 189
payments equilibrium. The equation for internal balance is set up as
follows:
( ) ( ) ( ), f Y  D  C G  I r G  X M D (1)
( , ). f Y  D G r (2)
The the slope of the f Y curve is negative as in (3),
( / ) 0. r g  D D  (3)
Equation (1) explains that aggregate demand D is equated to fullemployment
output supply. D is a function of household consumption
which is, in turn, a positive function of government spending G and the
corporate firm‘s investment I is negatively related to the rate of
interest, government spending, exports, and imports which are negatively
related to aggregate demand. Equation (1) can thus be reduced to (2).
Total differentiation of (2) yields the slope of the internal balance curve as
derived in (3). r D and g D refer to the partial derivative of aggregate
demand with respect to the rate of interest and to government spending
respectively. The external balance curve, on the other hand, is expressed as
in (4).
B  X M(D)  K(r). (4)
Equation (4) is the balance of payments which is a function of net exports,
X M(D) plus the balance of capital account transactions K(r). It is
assumed that import is a positive function of aggregate demand whereas
capital inflow is a positive function of the change in the domestic interest rate.
Total differentiation of (4) yields that the slope of the external balance curve
is positive as in (5),
190 Inchul Kim
Figure 3 Appropriate Use of Monetary and Fiscal Policy
( / )
0. r d r
g
K M D
D

 (5)
If the economy is at E with recession being a BOP surplus, it requires a
lower interest rate and greater government spending. If one compares (3)
and (5), the slope of the external balance curve is greater than that of the
internal balance curve. This is demonstrated in figure 3. In the G-r space,
there are four regions. Region I relates to inflation and the BOP surplus.
Region II includes inflation and the BOP deficit. Region III concerns
recession and the BOP deficit. Region IV entails recession and the BOP
surplus. At point E, both internal and external balances are simultaneously
achieved. If the economy is at E characterized by recession and surplus,
the government will want to increase its spending whereas the central bank
will want to lower the interest rate.
Alternatively, the government can achieve full employment and a trade
balance by using its spending and exchange rate policy. The internal and
G
0 r
Yf
Yf
B
B
E
Recession
Surplus(Ⅳ)
Inflation
Surplus(Ⅰ)
Inflation
Deficit(Ⅱ)
Recession
Deficit(Ⅲ)
E'
Korea’s Capitalistic Planning Model: Policy Lessons for Mongolia 191
external balance equations can be derived almost in the same manner as
before. This model has an important policy implication for Mongolia
because it can use its exchange rate as a policy instrument.
The internal balance equation can be expressed as (6). In (6) and (7), the
exchange rate enters the trade function as an argument.
( ) ( ) ( , ), f Y  D  C G  I G  X S M G S (6)
( , ). f Y  D G S (7)
Total differentiation of (7) yields that the slope of the internal balance
curve is negative as in (8),
( / ) 0. s g  D D  (8)
The external balance here is the trade balance only. If the interest rate
policy is not effective for some reasons, government spending is used with
the exchange rate policy as expressed in (9),
B  X(S) M(G, S). (9)
Setting the total differentiation of (14) to zero yields that the slope of the
external balance equation is positive as in (10),
( / ) 0. s g B B  (10)
Figure 4 shows the intersection of the two slopes. The internal balance
line is negatively sloped whereas the external balance line is positively
sloped. This policy-mix framework is readily applicable to a small
economy in a state of transition, as is the case with Mongolia. Suppose that
the Mongolian economy is placed in region II with inflation and trade deficit.
192 Inchul Kim
Figure 4 Appropriate Use of Fiscal and Exchange Rate Policy
It is then necessary to reduce its fiscal spending. However, it is not clear whether the Mongolian government should devalue or revalue its currency. If their economy is situated at point b, they do not need to undertake exchange rate policy. However, if the Mongolian economy is either at point ‗a‘ or at point ‗c‘, then the exchange rate authority must either devalue or revalue the Mongolian currency.
5. POLICY LESSONS FOR MONGOLIA
Mongolia is a small economy, being rich in natural resources including copper and gold. It has a comparative advantage in livestock herding given its vast land mass. To join a group of newly emerging economies in becoming an industrially advanced economy, Mongolia is required to design long term development plans.
Korea’s Capitalistic Planning Model: Policy Lessons for Mongolia 193
To this end, Mongolia can learn from Korea‘s lessons in development planning. Korea has experienced seven rounds of five year economic planning practices during 1962-1997. Korea adopted a capitalistic planning model comprised of six different organs: strong political leadership, economic planning agency, the mass media, think tanks, the budget office, and the statistical office. Of these six organs, presidential or political leadership is the most important. A shortage of domestic savings can be compensated for through foreign borrowing. Targets may be readjusted as necessary.
Mongolia is capable of simultaneously developing its rural and industrial sectors. In Korea‘s case, the labor migration strategy was successful due to surplus labor in the rural sector. In Mongolia‘s case, however, an abundance of natural resources in the rural sector prevents the ready adoption of the migration strategy. Compared to Korea‘s population of 50 million, Mongolia‘s 3 million is much smaller. Hence, it needs to develop the two sectors simultaneously.
Mongolia‘s economy was badly hit by the 2008 global financial crisis. Reduction in external demand caused a significant decline in its export revenue. Moreover, collapsing prices of mining products resulted in a recession and fiscal deficits. The Mongolian central bank may wish to devalue its currency for export promotion. To achieve this task, the Mongolian policy authorities will need to undertake a proper combination of fiscal spending and exchange rate policy.
As of 2008, the Mongolian economy experienced both inflation and trade deficits. If this situation were prevailing now, the government should certainly curtail its spending. However, it is not clear that Mongolia should devalue or alternatively revalue its currency. Any decision will be subject to the economy‘s exact location on the fiscal policy and exchange rate policy graph, even if it lies in the region of a recession and trade deficit. Policy experts will have to know the effectiveness of each of the two policies.
194 Inchul Kim
REFERENCES
Adelman, Irma, Practical Approaches to Development Planning, Korea’s Second Five-Year Plan, Johns Hopkins University Press, 1969.
Black, Stanley, ―Exchange Rate Policies for Less Developed Countries in a World of Floating Rates,‖ Essays in International Finance, 119, Princeton University, December 1976.
Cha, Dong-Se, Kwang Suk Kim, and Dwight H. Perkins, Korean Economy 1945-1995: Performance and Vision for the 21th Century, Seoul: Korea Development Institute (KDI), 1997.
EBRD, ―Macroeconomic Performance,‖ Mongolia Economic Overview, 2008 (http://www.ebrd.com/country/country/mongolia/econo.htm).
Kim, Dal Hyun, ―Korea‘s Five-Year Economic Development Plans: Targets, Performance and Overall Assessment,‖ Development Experience of the Korean Economy, Graduate School of Pan-Pacific International Studies Kyung Hee University, 2008, pp. 1-32.
Lewis, Arthur, ―Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labor,‖ The Manchester School, 22(2), 1954, pp. 139-191.
Mundell, Robert, ―The Appropriate Use of Monetary and Fiscal Policy for Internal and External Stability,‖ IMF Staff Papers, 9(1), March 1962, pp. 70-79.
Ninomiya, Kenshiro, ―Open Economy Financial Instability,‖ The Journal of Korean Economy, 8(2), 2007, pp. 329-355.
Todaro, Michael, Development Planning: Models and Methods, Oxford University Press, 1971.
World Bank, ―The Mongolia Monthly Economic Update,‖ 2009 (www. worldbank.org/mn).
Yi, Feng, Democracy, Governance, and Economic Performance: Theory and Evidence, MIT Press, 2003.

http://www.akes.or.kr/akes/downfile/7.Kim.pdf